Yesterday I reflected briefly on some of my book's ideas about the influence of context on institutional reforms in development. The book argues that many institutional reforms face limits because reformers overlook the change context.
I noted that this is often the case because reformers have solutions in mind before reforms begin, and these solutions cloud any view on contextual realities and how these might require different reform designs and a different reform approach in different contexts. I also noted, in the Korean example, that much of the contextual complexity reformers need to consider is out of sight to external observers anyway; informal norms and cultural cognitive scripts are unwritten and frequently unrecognized.
The book proposes ways of thinking about this issue and crafting reforms that actually work in complex contexts. A key idea is that problems provide entry points to tough contexts. More on this to follow in future blog postings.
Before getting to this, however, I wanted to propose a second reason why reforms are often limited in development. It also relates to the idea that reformers have pre-designed best practice solutions in mind. This does more than just blind reformers to the context, it also has reformers introducing highly specified content that is seldom supported in the countries undergoing reform.
These highly specified best practices often include particular kinds of laws and organizational forms that governments are encouraged to reproduce because they seemed to work elsewhere. Getting back to the example of Uganda and corruption, I would argue that anticorruption commissions were proposed as such 'best practices' in the 1990s. Many countries were encouraged to adopt these commissions, with the following example showing how African governments were 'carpet-bombed' with this practice at one stage:
www.u4.no/publications/measuring-success-in-five-african-anti-corruption-commissions/
The example that many countries were encouraged to follow was that of Hong Kong. A 2000 article in Finance and Development (by Jeremy Pope and Frank Vogl) points to this example as one other countries (like Nigeria, in the article) should follow [emphasis is mine]:
See:http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2000/06/pope.htm
Nigeria has a long way to go, but it can be encouraged by examples of
effective approaches in other countries. National anticorruption agencies, for
example, can go far beyond merely identifying and prosecuting corrupt officials,
vital as this is. They can also assist in creating an environment in which large
public works proceed without corruption. They can operate in ways that command
the respect of contractors and contribute to the building of a business
environment that is imbued with integrity. Although these aspirations sound
utopian, they can be realized, as Hong Kong SAR has demonstrated.
...
The ICAC [anticorruption commission] has been pivotal to the success of transparent public procurement in Hong Kong SAR.
Pope and Vogl point to specific evidence in the Hong Kong example to show how projects can be completed without corruption--under the auspices of an anticorruption commission. The example is one that I could see many countries showing interest in, centered as it is on infrastructure and development:
Michael Wiehen and Peter Rooke, members of Transparency International's Board
of Directors, recently examined the procurement processes involved in developing
Hong Kong SAR's Airport Core Program (ACP), which included construction of the
Hong Kong airport, as well as of high-speed rail and road connections, a major
suspension bridge, and a cross-harbor tunnel. The total capital cost of the ACP
exceeded HK$160 billion (US$20.6 billion at the current exchange rate of US$1 =
HK$7.75), making it one of the largest infrastructure projects ever undertaken
anywhere in the world. The ACP was virtually free of corruption...
The authors are obviously making an argument in favor of using anticorruption commissions to foster this kind of successful project. They then note some of the factors that made for an effective anticorruption commission and project in Hong Kong:
- Hong Kong SAR's clear, strict Prevention of Bribery Ordinance and strong
Independent Commission Against Corruption (ICAC), which has impressive legal
powers and a staff of about 1,350 professionals;
- clear rules and effective control mechanisms for selecting and procuring
consultant and construction services and equipment supplies, supervising and
monitoring the implementation of contracts, enforcing the accountability of
government staff as well as of consultants and contractors, and resolving
disputes;
- the establishment, for ACP purposes, of special institutions such as the New
Airport Projects Coordinating Office (since dissolved), which had a
dispute-resolution team that stepped in whenever problems occurred, and the
Engineering and Associated Consultant Selection Board, which is also involved in
non-ACP projects; and
- a favorable working environment, including appropriate salaries for civil
servants, a high degree of professionalism and pride among the officials, and a
relatively small society in which businessmen caught offering bribes or
otherwise trying to manipulate the processes find it difficult to obtain other
business, making corruption a high-risk activity.
The authors include a paragraph that focuses on the anticorruption commission alone, listing further factors that are important to consider in thinking of its success:
The ICAC has been pivotal to the success of transparent public procurement in
Hong Kong SAR. Its work is carried out by three departments. The Operations
Department carries out the investigation and prosecution of offenses; the
Corruption Prevention Department examines the practices and procedures of
government departments and public bodies and makes recommendations on how
opportunities for corruption can be eliminated or reduced; and the Community
Relations Department is responsible for educating the general public about the
evils of corruption, instilling positive values in Hong Kong's youth—starting as
early as kindergarten—providing advice to business organizations on drawing up
codes of conduct, and harnessing support for the ICAC.
I really like the piece by Pope and Vogl, because it gives hints as to the CONTENT required to make an anticorruption commission work. Consider some of the CONTENT requirements: Laws and ordinances; Multiple departments with over 1,000 staff (in Hong Kong, a city state), clear rules and procedures for doing day-to-day things like resolving disputes, inter-organizational structures to implement the new day-to-day procedures, and things they call "a favorable working environment", "a high degree of professionalism and pride among the officials" and social conditions and norms that "make corruption a high-risk activity."
This is a lot of CONTENT. A highly specified and demanding reform that takes a lot to work. So now we take this story to the many countries in which these commissions were introduced and I ask the question, "Which aspects of the content were actually introduced in the reforms?"
The answer, in many cases, is "very little." Laws, the anticorruption commission in itself...maybe some of the senior management. Sometimes the formal day-to-day procedures. Most interventions did not staff these commissions properly (because there were funding issues related to a lack of political support). Most of them did not build the inter-organizational structures that made a difference in Hong Kong. Most of them did very little to establish the "favorable working environment" and the informal 'rules of the game' associated with such.
I'm not saying that reforms could ever 'create' this kind of informal or political content. It does seem to me that the content is required to make this kind of intervention work, however. Without it, many anticorruption commissons have proved nothing more than shells--or iceberg tips without foundations. As I say in the book, these are the kinds of icebergs that sink.
And these kinds of reforms are limited. They impose highly specified best practice forms on countries. These require a lot of content to work. But reforms fail to provide the content required to make them work. So they fail.